Google, Alibaba, Global Antitrust Standard
People love a “missing billionaire” story, even when there isn’t one. That’s what many Western media outlets and some “Substack experts” have been hotly discussing lately: “Where is Jack Ma?” As Alibaba’s stock price gyrates, all this reminds me of was the false rumor about Warren Buffett’s declining health in 2000 that sent Berkshire stock to a 52-week low.
Ma is most likely just doing Tai Chi at home, during a time when no one in China is traveling abroad and there’s no Davos after party to go to anyway. Besides, laying low after a high-profiled speech is the smart thing to do; there’s nothing worth being public about right now.
Instead of wasting more energy “looking for” him, what’s perhaps more worthwhile to look into is China’s new antitrust regulatory framework. The most important document to understand is the “Antitrust Guidelines for the Platform Economy”, a draft policy released by the State Administration for Market Regulations. (The public commenting period is now over and the policies are in effect. I have put the official Chinese document in this Google Doc for easy reading and referencing.)
Antitrust investigations in the air everywhere, so it’s no longer strictly a national issue. Examining Google’s antitrust experience with what’s in the “Antitrust Guidelines for the Platform Economy” document, projecting what may happen to Alibaba, and thinking about whether a global antitrust standard can (or should) emerge is what I’ll focus on in this post today.
Google’s Antitrust Experience
Google has been the biggest antitrust target in the last 10 years, so its experience is the most instructive. Here’s a list of the major actions that have happened so far from the EU and US, noting the core complaints and timeline for reasons that will become apparent later:
- November 2010: the European Commission (EC) investigated Google’s search algorithm for favoring Google Shopping listings and downgrading third-party listings.
(Result: April 2015, formal complaint issued based on a 5-year investigation; June 2017, Google was fined €2.4 billion or $2.7 billion or roughly 2.5% of Google’s 2016 revenue.)
- April 2015: the EC started investigating Android for abusing its dominant market share to force smartphone makers to pre-install Google apps and services.
(Result: July 2018, Google was fined €4.3 billion or $5 billion or 4.5% of Google’s 2017 revenue; Google is appealing this fine.)
- July 2016: the EC issued a separate complaint derived from the same investigation from 2010 about Google forcing its direct partners to only use AdSense and no other competing advertising services.
(Result: March 2019, Google was fined €1.49 billion or $1.68 billion or roughly 1.2% of Google’s 2018 revenue.)
- October 2020: the US Department of Justice (DOJ) along with 11 Republican state attorneys general sued Google for pushing out competing search engines by, among other things, paying Apple roughly $12 billion each year to make Google the default option on Safari and iPhones.
(Result: pending, tentative trial start date is Sept 23, 2023(!))
- December 2020: a different group of more than 30 state attorneys general, led by Colorado and Nebraska, sued Google for mostly the same thing as the DOJ suit, except for one additional complaint about Google discriminating against the results of other “vertical” search services, like Yelp for restaurants and Kayak for travel.
(Result: this suit will likely be merged with the DOJ suit since the allegations are similar)
- December 2020: another smaller group of state attorneys general, led by Texas, sued Google for monopolistically controlling the entire digital advertising supply chain and allegedly making an illegal deal with Facebook to ease up competition in exchange for preferential auction treatment for Google’s ads listing.
(Result: pending)
I have painstakingly noted both the core complaint and timeline of each investigation to underscore two big lessons we should draw: the framework being applied to Google seems either ad-hoc or outdated, and the multi-year timeline is counterproductive to the goal of promoting competition -- a stated purposed in the current antitrust framework.
Let’s dig into each a bit more.
Framework Weakness
I’m not familiar with the European legal framework or tradition on antitrust -- a topic I need to learn more about. But the American one is based mostly on the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890. The target back then was Big Oil. This framework has persisted, so much so that the DOJ official announcement of its lawsuit proudly noted this tradition that broke up Standard Oil, AT&T, Microsoft, and now, potentially, Google.
The major purpose of the Sherman Act framework is to protect consumer welfare from companies who can increase prices when they reach monopolistic status. This way of thinking is rather outdated when applied to Internet companies, like Google and Amazon. The Internet is a free and open network that has enabled almost-instant delivery of products and services to billions of people. The dominant Internet services -- Google’s search, Amazon’s e-commerce, Facebook’s social network, etc. -- become dominant precisely because they are delivering valuable services to consumers that are either dirt cheap or completely free. In an antitrust framework focused on “consumer welfare protection”, it’s hard to pin down Big Tech, because it’s hard to argue against something clearly valuable that’s free. Unsurprisingly, that is Google’s most frequently used pushback against these investigations.
There is another goal to the current antitrust framework -- promoting competition, but that is still in support of the ultimate goal of protecting consumer welfare. The issue is we haven’t deeply re-examined the assumption that more competition will grow consumer welfare. It’s debatable whether Yelp is better for searching restaurants or Kayak is better for looking up flights compared to Google. (Personally, I have found Google’s flight search convenient and a breeze to use.) Of course, it’s valid to argue that Google became better precisely due to some anti-competitive behaviors. Or are those just valid competitive behaviors? That’s the hard question that the current framework is ill-equipped to answer.
The dilemma here is that harming competition does not necessarily reduce consumer welfare. So promoting competition for its own sake, which seems to be the intention of many of these investigations, seems to miss the point.
Even if we assume that more competition is good overall, thus worth pursuing on its own merit, the execution of these investigations is doing a poor job of delivering on that goal. The timeline is so long it’s becoming counterproductive.
Long Timeline
Whether it’s the EC or the US DOJ, they all seem to operate on a multi-year timeline. While these investigations should be thorough and not rushed, the current speed (or lack thereof) is literally killing startups’ capacity to compete.
Most startups die well before they reach five years old. And if you are a startup whose product or service bumps up against Google, leading you to file an antitrust complaint, your chances of survival is already slim. The best case outcome may be to just get acquired by Google, while complaining about Google.
Having taken up the mantle first, the EC’s initial five year investigation may be warranted. But there does not seem to be much exchange or transfer in knowledge from the European investigations to the American ones to speed things up, even though the essence of the American complaints are not that different. The almost three-year period between the DOJ’s announcement and the first trial date seems unfathomable.
Meanwhile, a company as wealthy as Google can keep many antitrust lawyers gainfully employed, let these investigations slowly play out, and continue its current behaviors and make money hand over fist. (As far as I can tell, there’s no preemptive injunction to any of the alleged anti-competitive behaviors in the pending lawsuits.) And the startups who are being outcompeted, fairly or unfairly, can either wait, pivot, or die.
The Sherman Act framework is a legacy that needs to be adapted to the 21st century. Its execution can also use some 21st century speed to match the pace that its Big Tech targets are moving. What this regulatory system could use is a set of clear, detailed rules and anti-competitive behaviors that are tailored to how Internet platforms operate.
That's where the Chinese antitrust framework could come in.
Being an old civilization but a young country, China does not have much experience or legacy when it comes to antitrust. It didn’t have Big Oil, Big Tobacco, AT&T or Microsoft. That youth has its pros and cons, as I noted in “Alibaba and Antitrust with Chinese Characteristics.” China’s antitrust regulations are being developed mostly from scratch and have been a muddy picture until late last year.
Now that the policies are more clear, are there parts that the US and EU jurisdictions should reference to better evolve their own frameworks?
Alibaba and China’s New Regulations
To see whether there’s anything worth referencing, let’s look into some specific sections of the “Antitrust Guidelines for the Platform Economy” document in more detail.
This document is tailored to specifically target the behaviors of Chinese Internet companies, not a general framework to cover the entire Chinese economy. That may be by design, because many sectors are state-owned and thus definitionally monopolistic. It’s a real life outcome of the pros and cons mixed together. The pros are the rules are very up-to-date with how the Internet economy and tech platforms work. The cons are it conveniently leaves out other monopolistic industries.
For the purpose of exchange rulemaking practices, I do think there are sections worth studying for US and EU regulators. In particular, Chapter Three on “Abusive Behaviors from Dominant Market Position” outlines many types of anti-competitive behaviors.
Here’s a few sections from Chapter Three I’d like to highlight:
- Section 13: “Selling below cost” (If this rule was part of the US antitrust framework 20 years ago, Amazon’s strategy that squeezed out Diapers.com would’ve been illegal.)
- Section 14: “Refusal to Transact” (This section would cover the EC’s complaint in 2016 Google forcing direct partners to only use AdSense.)
- Section 15: “Restrictions to Transact” (This section mentions the “choose one out of two” practice, which is the basis for investigating Alibaba. Other parts of this section would cover the EC’s 2010 complaint regarding favoring Google Shopping and the US lawsuit about discriminating against the likes of Yelp and Kayak.)
The entire Chapter Three is worth reading for a painstakingly detailed catalogue of what is anti-competitive and how you can tell. The rules are applicable to antitrust situations outside of China, because Chinese tech giants closely study the strategies of the American giants. Increasingly, the reverse is happening as well. The playground for Big Tech everywhere is global, not national.
Of course, writing rules is the easy part, especially when the target is obvious. Promulgating, implementing, and adjudicating complaints fairly and quickly based on the rules is the real test. The Chinese regulators’ first test is their investigation of Alibaba, announced on last Christmas Eve.
Given how closely tailored the rules are, it’s almost certain that Alibaba will be found guilty. What’s important to watch is speed, reasoning, and effect on the market afterward. If the Alibaba investigation can be concluded by the end of 2021, with a clear set of generalizable rationale and a real shift in China tech’s competitive dynamic, that would be a more successful execution than what has happened so far in the EU and US.
Need for Global Antitrust Standard
Laws and regulations always lag behind technology, as it should in order to not thwart innovation. The hard problem to solve is when and how quickly they should catch up. And the best way to catch up is to learn from others and not reinvent the wheel.
China has been learning from both the US and EU. This is evident in the People’s Daily column commenting on the Alibaba antitrust probe, where both the US antitrust investigations and the EC’s fines of Google were referenced. If there’s something worth leveraging from what China is doing, it’d be smart (and only fair) for American and European regulators to do the same. Not only would this type of rule-making exchange benefit each respective jurisdiction, it would help establish a global antitrust standard that is badly needed.
Big Tech from the US, China, and possibly from elsewhere in the future are already mimicking each other. Without a global standard that’s globally applied, they will continue to do what they do, just in different locations -- an infinite game of worldwide whack-a-mole.
Based on my personal experience in government, middle and senior-level rulemakers are quite willing to engage with and learn from similarly ranked officials from other countries, because most of them are technocratic civil servants, not showy politicians. They genuinely care about writing good rules!
As multiple antitrust investigations proceed in parallel, I believe the raw materials for establishing a global standard already exist. Such a standard can and should emerge. The hurdle now is will politicians stop politicizing every government-to-government exchange, step out of the way, and let the rulemakers make rules.
If you like what you've read, please SUBSCRIBE to the Interconnected email list. To read all previous posts, please check out the Archive section. New content will be delivered to your inbox (twice per week). Follow and interact with me on: Twitter, LinkedIn.
谷歌、阿里巴巴、全球反垄断标准
大家都喜欢看 "富翁失踪" 的故事,就算故事根本不存在。这也是众多西方媒体和一些 "Substack专家" 最近的热论:"马云在哪里?" 阿里的股价随即波动,这一切让我想起了2000年巴菲特身体不好的虚假传闻,导致Berkshire的股价当时跌到了52周的新低点。
马云很可能只是在家里打太极。这段时间中国没有人出国,本来也没有达沃斯峰会后的各种名流派对可去。此外,高调演讲后低调些也是明智之举,现在没有什么值得高调的事情了。
与其浪费更多的精力去 "找马云",不如看看更研究的新出炉的中国反垄断监管框架。最需要了解的文件是国家市场监管总局发布的《关于平台经济领域的反垄断指南》。(公开征求意见期已经结束,政策开始生效。我把指南全文放在了这个Google Doc里,方便您阅读和参考。)
全球各地的反垄断调查风起云涌,严格意义上反垄断已经不是某个国家国内的问题了。用《反垄断指南》中的内容来与谷歌的反垄断经历做对比,看看阿里未来的命运,并思考能否(或应不应该)有一个全球反垄断标准,是今天这篇文章的重点。
谷歌反垄断的经历
过去10年,谷歌一直是最大的反垄断调查目标,所以它的经验也最有借鉴意义。以下是目前欧盟和美国对谷歌的主要反垄断行动。我尤其注重总结了投诉的核心问题和调查的时间线,其原因晚一点揭晓。
- 2010年11月:欧盟委员会调查了谷歌的搜索算法,因为它偏重于谷歌自己的购物列表(Google Shopping),故意降低第三方列表。
(结果:2015年4月,在长达5年调查的基础上发出正式投诉;2017年6月,谷歌被罚款24亿欧元,约27亿美元,约占谷歌2016年营收的2.5%。)
- 2015年4月:欧委会开始调查安卓系统滥用其主导市场份额,强迫手机制造商预装谷歌app和服务。
(结果:2018年7月,谷歌被罚款43亿欧元(约50亿美元,占谷歌2017年营收的4.5%);谷歌正在对这一罚款进行上诉。)
- 2016年7月:欧委会发起一项新的投诉,内容源于2010年的调查,关于谷歌强迫其直接合作伙伴使用AdSense,不许用其他广告服务。
(结果:2019年3月,谷歌被罚款14.9亿欧元,约16.8亿美元,约占谷歌2018年营收的1.2%。)
- 2020年10月:美国司法部 (DOJ) 与11个共和党州检察长共同起诉谷歌,认为谷歌通过各种手法,包括每年向苹果支付约120亿美元,让谷歌成为Safari和iPhone上的默认搜索选项,将竞争对手赶出局。
(结果:未决,暂定开庭日期为2023年9月23日!)
- 2020年12月:以科罗拉多州和内布拉斯加州为首的30多个州总检察长组成的另一个团体起诉谷歌,理由与司法部的诉讼基本相同,只是多了一个关于谷歌歧视其他 "垂直" 搜索服务的投诉,比如用Yelp搜索餐馆和用Kayak搜索机票旅行。
(结果:由于诉讼内容相似,很可能会与DOJ的诉讼合并。)
- 2020年12月:以德克萨斯州为首的另一个较小的州检察长团体起诉谷歌垄断性控制了整个线上广告供应链,并涉嫌与Facebook进行非法交易,故意缓解竞争来换取在谷歌广告拍卖中的优惠待遇。
(结果:未决)
我不厌其烦地总结了每项调查的核心申诉问题和它们的时间线,是想强调应该吸取的两大教训:对谷歌使用的法律框架似乎很随意或者很过时,而长达多年的调查时间对促进竞争这个反垄断目标之一,最终是适得其反的。
我们来更深入的探讨一下这两个问题。
框架弱点
我对欧洲的反垄断法律框架和传统并不熟悉,还需要花些时间去了解。但美国的框架主要基于1890年通过的《Sherman反垄断法》。当时的目标是大石油公司。这个框架一直延续了下来,以至于司法部对谷歌诉讼的官宣里自豪地指出,这个传统打散了Standard Oil、AT&T、微软,现在还有可能打散了谷歌。
基于《Sherman反垄断法》的框架的主要目的是保护消费者利益,使大众免受有了垄断性市场份额后的公司可以随意涨价的迫害。这种思维方式用在像谷歌和亚马逊这种互联网公司上就有些过时了。互联网是一个自由开放的网络,使全球数十亿人可以即时获得很多产品和服务。占主导地位的互联网服务 -- 谷歌的搜索、亚马逊的电商、Facebook的社交网络等 -- 之所以能成为主导,正是因为它们向消费者提供了有价值的服务。而这些服务要么非常便宜,要么完全免费。在注重 "保护消费者利益" 的反垄断框架下,很难有效制约这些巨头,因为有价值的“免费”东西是很难反驳的。不出所料,这正是谷歌对各种反垄断调查最常用的反击。
当前的反垄断框架还有另一个目标,那就是“促进竞争”,但它还是为了支持"保护消费者利益"这一最终目标。问题是我们并没有深刻地重新审视竞争越多消费者利益就会越多的这项假设。与谷歌相比,Yelp是否在搜索餐馆上更好用,Kayak是否在搜索航班上更好用,这是值得商榷的。(就我个人经验而言,我发现谷歌的航班搜索很方便,很好用。) 当然,另一个同样合理的问题,就是如果谷歌没有对这些竞争对手做出反竞争行为,它本身的服务是不是就不会那么好?还是说谷歌的做法其实是正当的竞争行为?这是个很难回答的问题,而目前的框架不具备能回答这个问题的能力。
难就难在,损害竞争并不一定会降低消费者利益。所以,仅为了促进竞争而促进竞争(看似也是许多调查的意图),似乎没有抓住重点。
即使我们假设更多的竞争总体上是好事,因此值得保护和追求,那这些调查的执行步伐目前很难实现这一目标,时间线拉的太长,已经变得适得其反。
漫长的调查时间
无论是欧委员会还是美国司法部,它们似乎都是以好几年的节奏来运作。虽然这些调查应该是彻底的,不应该仓促,但目前的速度(或缓慢程度)实际上正在扼杀创业公司的竞争力。
大多数创业公司在成立5内就死了。如果你的初创公司的产品或服务与谷歌直接碰撞,导致需要提出反垄断申诉,那生存机率就更小了。最好的结果很可能就是一边投诉谷歌,一边最终被谷歌收购。
做为打响调查谷歌的“第一枪”,欧委会最初的五年调查期也许是合理的,有必要的。但从欧洲到美国,似乎并没有太多的知识转移,以加快调查的进度,尽管美国方面投诉的核心内容并没有太大的区别。从司法部的公告到第一次开庭的日期,要等近三年的时间,似乎让人难以理解。
像谷歌这么有钱的公司,可以高薪养着许多反垄断律师,让这些调查慢慢地进行,并继续其目前的各种做法,继续赚大钱。(据我所知,在未决的诉讼中,并没有对任何对涉嫌反竞争行为的提前禁令)。而那些即将被击败的创业公司(不管手法公平不公平),要么等待,要么转型,要么死亡。
Sherman反垄断法框架是个需要适应21世纪的法律“古董” 。它的执行方法也需要一些21世纪的速度,才能跟上它企图管制的科技巨头们的发展速度。这套监管体系可以吸收一套针对互联网平台运作方式而制定的明确详细的规则和非法反竞争行为。
这也许就是中国反垄断框架可以发挥作用的地方。
中国既是一个古老的文明,也是一个年轻的国家。在反垄断方面,中国并没有太多的经验和法律遗产。它没有大石油、大烟草、AT&T或微软。正如我在《阿里巴巴与有中国特色的反垄断》 中指出的,这种“年轻”有利有弊。中国的反垄断法规大多是从零开始制定的,直到去年年底之前,内容还很模糊。
现在政策比较明确了,是否有值得美国和欧盟监管者参考的部分,以更好地完善自己的框架呢?
阿里与中国的反垄断新规
为了讨论是否有参考价值这个问题,我们需要详细了解一下《反垄断指南》的内容。
《反垄断指南》是专门针对中国互联网公司和平台的行为而制定的,并不覆盖中国经济整体。这可能也是有意的,因为许多行业都是国有的,本质上就有垄断性。这就是利弊混在一起的结果。“利“即是规则很符合互联网经济和平台的运作方式。“弊”即是它顺手避开了其他也有垄断性的行业。
对于借鉴规则制定和实践的交流,我觉得美国和欧盟的监管者确实有值得研究的章节,尤其是第三章,关于“滥用市场支配地位行为”。它概述了很多类型的反竞争行为。
下面是第三章中我想重点介绍的几条:
- 第十三条 “低于成本销售”(如果这条规则是20年前美国反垄断框架的一部分,亚马逊挤掉Diapers.com的策略就是非法的了)。
- 第十四条 “拒绝交易” (这一条可以涵盖欧委会在2016年谷歌强迫直接合作伙伴只使用AdSense的投诉)。
- 第十五条 “限定交易”(这一条明确提到了 "二选一 ",是调查阿里的法律基础。本条其他部分可以覆盖2010年欧委会关于偏袒谷歌购物的投诉,以及美国关于歧视Yelp和Kayak等公司的诉讼)。
第三章整篇都值得一读,它对什么是不公平竞争行为,以及如何判断这种行为的存在有很细致的列表。这些规则之所以适用于中国境外公司的反垄断行为,是因为中国科技巨头密切研究美国巨头的战略打法。最近相反方向的“学习” 也越来越多。各地科技巨头的市场都是全球的,不仅限于某个国家。
当然,写规则相对容易,尤其是当目标很明显的时候。根据规则公平、迅速地颁布、执行和裁决投诉才是真正的考验。中国监管机构的第一个考验即是在去年圣诞节前夕宣布的对阿里巴巴的调查。
考虑这套新规则的针对性,阿里被判触犯“二选一”这种垄断行为几乎没什么悬念。更值得注意的是看整个过程的速度、公正性,以及判决后对市场的影响。如果阿里的调查能在2021年年底前结束,并有一套清晰的可推广的解释,中国科技的竞争态势也能真正发生转变,那将比欧盟和美国目前的调查更成功。
需要制定全球反垄断标准
法律和法规总是落后于技术,为了不阻碍创新,也应该如此。困难的是,法律和法规应该在什么时候和多快去赶上。而最好的追赶方式一般是向别人学习,而不是自己重新造轮子。
中国一直在向美国和欧盟学习。这一点从《人民日报》评论阿里反垄断调查的专栏中可以看出,美国的反垄断调查和欧委会对谷歌的罚款都被提及。如果中国的做法有值得借鉴的地方,那么美国和欧洲的监管机构也理所当让应该借鉴,这才是明智的(也是公平的)。这种对规则制定的交流不仅会让各自的司法管辖区受益,还将有助于建立一个急需的全球反垄断标准。
来自美国、中国以及未来可能来自其他地方的科技巨头已经在相互模仿。如果没有一个全球适用的标准,它们将继续做它们想做的事情,只是在不同的地方。这将是一个无限的全球捶打游戏。
根据我个人在政府工作的经验,中高级别的规则政策制定者很愿意与其他国家同样级别的官员接触和学习,因为他们中的大多数是技术官僚公务员,而不是喜欢炫耀的政客。他们真正关心怎么把规则写好!
随着多项反垄断调查的同时进行,我觉得建立全球反垄断标准的原材料已经存在。这种标准可以存在,也需要存在。现在的障碍是,政治家们是否可以不要把每一次政府之间的交流都政治化,让开路,让规则制定者好好制定规则。
如果您喜欢所读的内容,请用email订阅加入“互联”。要想读以前的文章,请查阅《互联档案》。每周两次,新的文章将会直接送达您的邮箱。请在Twitter、LinkedIn上给个follow,和我交流互动!